OCTOBER 28, 1793:
Eli
Whitney, a Massachusetts inventor, applied for a patent on his “cotton gin.”
This “gin” (or engine) was designed to simplify the laborious process of
separating cotton seeds from cotton fibers, a process without which the cotton
is useless.
Prior to the invention of the cotton gin it took a single slave
about ten hours to separate a single pound of fiber from the seeds. This
rendered cotton cultivation financially infeasible as most growers could not
afford the labor-intensive cost of raising and preparing cotton for market.
Slavery was, in fact, dying out, both North and South, since the expense of
keeping slaves exceeded their return on value. In 1793, there were only 700,000 slaves in the United States.
With the invention of the gin, a
team of two or three slaves could produce around fifty pounds of cotton in just
one day.
Cotton cultivation boomed exponentially, and so did the call for
slaves in the South. By 1861, there were 4.3 million slaves in the country. Marginal planters became rich. Rich planters became
wealthy. And wealthy planters became politically powerful. As a result,
pressure began to build in Washington D.C. to open land in the new Territories
to cotton (and hence slavery).
These 4,300,000 slaves were
owned by a coterie of some 300,000 slaveowners. Most slaveowners owned only a
small number of slaves. The fantasy of “Tara,” with fields full of diligently
working blacks was for the most part just that, a fantasy. However, smallholding
slaveowners were tacitly encouraged to view themselves as gentleman farmers by
the wealthy planter class so that the planter class could maintain its iron
grip on the south’s economic and social structures.
For the smallholding
slaveowner, slaves were, like other property, often inherited from parents and
grandparents along with the farmstead and the house. Southerners as a rule
liked to characterize the master and slave relationship as one that transcended
generational lines, a kind of symbiotic relationship through which both slave
and master profited.
The reality was far
different. Slaves were expensive to purchase (upwards of $1,000 per person in
1860 or close to $30,000 in 2010 dollars), and expensive to own, given the needs of food, shelter, clothing and
medical care. For the smallholding slave
owner, slaves were often their major lifetime investment (much as a home is for
the modern American family). Most slaveowners were, like farmers throughout
history, frequently cash poor, often indebted, commonly carrying property
mortgages, and at the mercy of the weather to produce a good crop. In bad
seasons and good, slaves represented a form of fungible wealth which could be
sold, traded or even rented out for income. This, in part, explains
the vehemence of most slaveholders against the abolitionist movement which
meant to strip slaveholders of such liquidity as they had. In short, the
surrender of slave property would lead to their economic devastation. Even a
partial compensation plan (as Abraham Lincoln posited several times during the
Civil War) was a gateway to tremendous economic losses.
Slaves were all too frequently
sold for quick cash: “extra” children became a source or ready cash,
hardworking skilled fathers brought premium prices, and young women of
childbearing age were in demand for owners who wished to increase their
slaveholdings cheaply. This vision of
slaves as inanimate property exploded the structure of slave families, and had
a multigenerational densensitizing impact on southern whites.
Distribution of Slaveholders by
Size of Holdings, 1860 *
|
TOTAL SLAVEHOLDERS
|
OWNERS OF 1-4 SLAVES
|
OWNERS OF 5-19 SLAVES
|
OWNERS OF 20-49 SLAVES
|
OWNERS OF 50-99 SLAVES
|
OWNERS OF 100-499 SLAVES
|
OWNERS OF 500+ SLAVES
|
|
A
L
|
33,730
|
14,404 (42.7%)
|
13,295 (39.4%)
|
4,344 (12.9%)
|
1,341 (4.0%)
|
346 (1.0%)
|
-
|
A
R
|
1,149
|
659 (57.4%)
|
424
(36.9%)
|
56 (4.9%)
|
10 (0.9%)
|
-
|
-
|
F
L
|
5,152
|
2,233 (43.3%)
|
2,111 (41.0%)
|
603 (11.7%)
|
158 (3.1%)
|
47 (0.9%)
|
-
|
G
A
|
41,084
|
17,534 (42.7%)
|
17,187 (41.8%)
|
5,049 (12.3%)
|
1,102 (2.7%)
|
211 (0.5%)
|
1
|
L
A
|
22,033
|
10,235 (46.5%)
|
7,873 (35.7%)
|
2,349 (10.7%)
|
1,029 (4.7%)
|
543 (2.5%)
|
4
|
M
S
|
30,943
|
12,689 (41.0%)
|
12,359 (39.9%)
|
4,220 13.6(%)
|
1,359 (4.4%)
|
315 (1.0%)
|
1
|
N
C
|
34,658
|
16,071 (46.4%)
|
14,522 (41.9%)
|
3,321 (9.6%)
|
611 (1.8%)
|
133 (0.4%)
|
-
|
S
C
|
26,701
|
10,017 (37.5%)
|
11,392 (42.7%)
|
3,646 (13.7%)
|
1,197 (4.5%)
|
441 (1.7%)
|
8
|
T
N
|
36,844
|
19,179 (52.1%)
|
14,553 (39.5%)
|
2,550 (6.9%)
|
335 (0.9%)
|
47 (0.1%)
|
-
|
T
X
|
21,878
|
11,342 (51.8%)
|
8,373 (38.3%)
|
1,827 (8.4%)
|
282 (1.3%)
|
54 (0.2%)
|
-
|
V
A
|
52,128
|
25,355 (48.6%)
|
20,996 (40.3%)
|
4,917 (9.4%)
|
746 (1.4%)
|
114 (0.2%)
|
-
|
T
O
T
A
L
|
306,300
|
139,718 (45.6%)
|
123,085 (40.2%)
|
32,882 (10.7%)
|
8,170 (2.7%)
|
2,251 (0.7%)
|
14
|
As can be seen from the
above chart (based on the U.S. Eighth Decennial Census, 1860) only 1% of slaveowners
owned more than 50 slaves, and those who owned many hundreds could easily be
gathered ‘round one dining table of the time (as they sometimes were). In
large part, these “1%ers”, with their disparate economic power and political
and social influence, were the driving force behind secessionism.
No comments:
Post a Comment